|
|
|
Rudolf Steiner e.Lib
|
|
World Economy
Rudolf Steiner e.Lib Document
|
|
World Economy
Schmidt Number: S-4917
On-line since: 13th November, 2000
Dornach, 29th July, 1922.
You know, perhaps, that in my Threefold Commonwealth I
endeavoured to express in a formula how we may arrive at a conception
of true price (as we will call it to begin with) in the
whole economic process. Needless to say to begin with, such a
formula is only an abstraction. And it is the object of these lectures
(which, I believe, in spite of the shortness of the time, will really
form a whole) it is our very object in these lectures to work
the whole science of Economics, at any rate in outline, into this
abstraction.
The formula which I gave in my Threefold Commonwealth was as
follows: A true price is forthcoming when a man receives, as
counter-value for the product he has made, sufficient to enable him to
satisfy the whole of his needs, including of course the needs
of his dependants, until he will again have completed a like
product. Abstract as it is, this formula is none the less
exhaustive. In setting up a formula it is always necessary that it
should contain all the concrete details. I do believe, for the
domain of economics, this formula is no less exhaustive than, say, the
Theorem of Pythagoras is for all right-angled triangles. But the point
is just as we have to introduce into the Theorem of Pythagoras
the varying proportions of the sides, so shall we have to introduce
many, very many more variables into this formula. Economic Science is
precisely an understanding of how the whole economic process can be
included in this formula.
Today I intend to start from one essential feature of the formula. It
is this. The formula does not point to what is past but to what is
going to happen in the future, for I say in it, of set purpose,
the counter-value must satisfy the man's needs in the future
namely, until he will have made a like product again.
This is an absolutely essential feature of the formula. If we were to
demand a counter-value, literally, for the product which the man has
already finished if we expected this to be true to the
real economic facts it might well happen that he would receive
a value which would only satisfy his needs, say, for five-sixths of
the time which he will take in finishing the new product. For the
economic facts alter from the past into the future. He who imagines
that he can draw up any kind of table from the past, will invariably
go wrong in economics. Economic or business life essentially consists
in setting future processes in motion with the help of what went
before. But where past processes are thus used to set future ones in
motion, it inevitably happens in some cases that the values are
considerably shifted. Indeed they are constantly shifting. Hence in
this formula it is essential to say: If someone makes a pair of
boots, the time he took to make them is not the determining
factor in the economic sense. The determining factor is the time he
will take to make the next pair of boots. That is the
point, and we must now try to understand its fuller implications
within the whole economic process.
Yesterday we brought before our minds this cycle (see
Diagram 3):
Nature, Labour, Capital that is, Capital endued with value by
the Spirit. At this point I might just as well write (instead of
Capital) Spirit. To begin with we followed
out the economic process in this direction, counter-clockwise, and we
found that at this point congestion must not be allowed to occur. On
the contrary only so much must be allowed to go through as will act as
a kind of seed to carry on the process. A state of economic congestion
must not be allowed to arise through a fixation of Capital in ground
rents. Now, as I said, fundamentally speaking, the return for land
when it is sold i.e., when land is given a value in the
economic process works in direct opposition to the interests of
a person engaged in the manufacture of valuable goods. For if a
man wishes to manufacture valuable goods with the help of Capital, it
is to his interest that the rate of interest should be low. Having
less interest to pay, he will be less hampered in his use of the
Capital he has borrowed. The landowner, on the other hand (I may go
fully into these things, as they are of economic significance), the
landowner, or anyone who has an interest in the land becoming dearer,
will be able to make it dearer simply by a reduction in the rate of
interest. If he has a low rate of interest to pay, the value of his
land will grow, it will become dearer and dearer. Whereas a man
engaged in the manufacture of valuable commodities will be able to
make them cheaper because of a low rate of interest. Commodities,
therefore, which depend mainly on manufacture, become cheaper when the
rate of interest is low. Land, on the other hand, which gives a yield
without first having to be manufactured, becomes dearer when the rate
of interest is low. You can easily work it out. It is an economic
fact.
It would appear then to be necessary to arrange for two different
rates of interest: We ought to have a rate of interest as low as
possible for the installation of works for the production of valuable
commodities; and a rate of interest as high as possible for everything
that falls under the heading of land. This follows
directly from what we said before. We want a rate of interest as high
as possible for all that comes under the heading of
land. But that is a thing which cannot easily be carried
out in practice. A slightly higher rate of interest for Capital
advanced on land might be practicable, but this would be of little
help. A considerably higher rate of interest say, for instance,
the rate of interest which would keep the land at an ever constant
value, namely, 100% would be extremely difficult to realise in
practice without taking additional steps. 100% interest for money
borrowed on land would mend matters at once, but it cannot be carried
out in practice. In all such cases, the first point is to see with
full clarity into the economic process. When we do so, we soon realise
that the life of Associations is the only thing that can make it
healthy. Rightly to see the economic process will lead to our
being able rightly to direct it.
In the economic process we must speak, as I indicated yesterday, of
Production and Consumption. We must observe the producing and the
consuming process. This contrast has played a great part recently in
various much-canvassed economic theories which in due course have been
used for purposes of agitation. There has especially been much dispute
upon the question, whether spiritual or intellectual work, as
such, is in any way value-creating in the economic sphere.
The spiritual worker is certainly a consumer. Whether he is also a
producer in the economic sense is a question which has been much
discussed. The extreme Marxists, for example, have again and again
cited that luckless fellow, the Indian book-keeper, who has to keep
the accounts for his village community. He does not till the fields or
do any other productive work; he merely registers the productive work
done by others. The Marxists deny him the faculty of producing
anything. They declare that he is simply and solely maintained out of
the surplus value which the productive workers create. This worthy
book-keeper is worked as hard in Economics as Caius is in the formal
Logic which we did at college. Caius's job is proving the mortality of
man. You remember: All men are mortal, Caius is a man,
therefore Caius is mortal. His everlasting function of proving
the mortality of man has made him immortal in the world of Logic. The
same thing has happened in Marxian literature to the Indian bookkeeper
who is maintained simply by the surplus value of the productive
workers. He has become a classic.
This question is, if I may say so, extraordinarily full of
snags, in which we very easily get caught when we try to
work it out economically. I mean the question: How far (if at all)
spiritual work is economically productive? Now here it is especially
important to distinguish between the past and the future. For if you
consider, if you reflect statistically on, the past only, with respect
to the past and to all that is only the unbroken continuation
of the past, you will be able to prove that spiritual work is
unproductive. From the past into the future within the material
sphere, only purely material work and its effects can be held to be
productive in the economic process. It is quite a different matter
when you turn your eye to the future. And, as we said, to be engaged
in economics is to be working from the past into the future.
You need only think of this simple instance. Assume that in some
village a craftsman, who manufactures this or that, falls ill. Under
certain given circumstances let us say, if he falls into the
hands of an unskilful doctor he will have to lie in bed for
three weeks, during which time he will be able to do nothing. He will
disturb the economic process to no small extent. If he is a cobbler,
for three weeks long the boots and shoes will not be brought to market
taking the word market in the widest sense. But
now suppose he gets a very skilful doctor who makes him well in a
week. He can go back to work again in a week. In all seriousness you
can now decide the question: Who made the boots for the remaining 14
days, the cobbler or the doctor? In reality it was the doctor. And now
the thing is altogether clear. As soon as you take into account the
future from any given moment onward towards the future
you can no longer call the Spiritual unproductive. In relation to the
past, the Spiritual or rather, those human beings who work in
the spiritual sphere are consumers only. In relation to the
future they are decidedly productive, indeed they are the
producers, for they transform the whole process of production and make
it pronouncedly different for the economic life. You can see this from
the example of the tunnel. What happens when tunnels are built
nowadays? They could
not be built unless the differential calculus had been discovered. To
this day, therefore, Leibnitz is helping to build all tunnels. The way
prices work out in this case has really been determined by that
exertion of his spiritual forces. You can never answer these questions
in Economics if you consider the past in the same way as the future.
But, ladies and gentlemen, life does not move towards the past, nor
does it even prolong the past; it goes on into the future.
Hence no economic thought is real which does not reckon with what is
done by spiritual work, if we may call it so, that is to say,
fundamentally by thinking. But spiritual work is not an easy thing to
grasp. It has its own peculiar properties which are not at all easy to
grasp in economic terms. Spiritual work begins the moment work itself
that is to say, Labour is organised. The organising work
of thinking begins the very moment Labour itself is organised and
divided. Thenceforward, it grows more and more independent. Consider
the spiritual work of one who directs some undertaking within the
material sphere. You will see that he applies an immense amount of
spiritual work. Nevertheless he is still working with the resources
with which the economic process provides him as from the past. But
even on quite practical grounds you cannot get around the fact that
the sphere of spiritual activity (if I may now call it
activity instead of work or labour) also includes the
entirely free kind of activity. When a man invents the differential
calculus, and even more so when he paints a picture, there we have a
case of entirely free spiritual activity. At any rate, relatively
speaking, we can call it free. For whatever materials are derived from
the past the paints and the like they no longer have the
same significance in relation to the eventual products as do the raw
products, for example, purchased for material manufacture.
Passing into this region, therefore (see
Diagram 4), we come into the
sphere of the completely free spiritual life. In this sphere we find,
above all things, teaching and education. Those who have to teach and
educate stand undoubtedly within the sphere of the completely free
spiritual life. For the purely material economic process, it is
especially the free spiritual workers who are, in relation to the
past, absolutely and exclusively consumers. Of course, you may say,
they produce something, and, if they are painters, for example, they
are even paid something for what they have produced. In appearance,
therefore, the economic process is the same as when I manufacture a
table and sell it. And yet the process is essentially different as
soon as we cease to consider the buying and selling of the individual
and turn our attention to the economic organism as a whole and
this is what we must do in the present advanced stage of division of
Labour.
Now there are also pure consumers of another kind within a social
organism, namely, the young and the very old. Up to a certain age, the
young are pure consumers; and those who have been pensioned off are
again pure consumers. A very little reflection will suffice to
convince you that if there were no pure consumers in the economic
process mere consumers who are not producers at all
the thing could not go forward at all. For if everyone were producing,
all that is produced could not be consumed if the economic process
were to go forward at all. It is so at any rate as human life is, and
human life is not purely economics; it must be taken as a whole. The
real advancement of the economic process is only possible if it
includes pure consumers.
But I must now illumine from a different angle this fact: that we have
pure consumers within the economic process.
You see, this circle (in the diagram) can be made very instructive. We
can endow it with all manner of properties, and the question will
always be, how to bring the several economic processes and facts into
this circle, which represents for us the cycle of the economic
process. Something very important happens when, in buying and selling
in the market, I pay on the spot for what I get. The point is not that
I pay for it with money; I might equally well barter it for a
corresponding commodity which the other person was willing to accept.
The point is that I pay at once. Indeed it is this that
constitutes paying in the proper sense of the word. Now
here once more we must pass from the ordinary, everyday conception to
the true economic conception. For in the economic life the several
concepts constantly play into one another. The total phenomenon, the
total fact, results from the interplay of the most diverse factors.
You may say: It is conceivable that some regulation should be
made, so that no one need ever pay cash down; then there would be no
such thing as paying at once; one would only pay after a month or
after some other interval of time. But the point is this: We
are forming our concepts altogether wrongly when we say:
Some-one hands me a suit of clothes and I pay for it after a
month. The fact is that after a month I no longer pay for this
suit of clothes alone. In that moment I am paying for something quite
different. I am paying for something which circumstances, by raising
or lowering prices, may have made quite different. I am paying for an
ideal element in addition. In fact, we cannot do without the concept
of immediate payment. This is the concept which holds
good in cases of simple purchase. Nay more, a thing becomes a
commodity on the market through the very fact that it is paid for at
once. This is generally the case with those commodities which are
Nature transformed by Labour. For such commodities I
pay. Here payment plays the essential part. There must be such
payment. I pay at the very moment when I open my purse and give away
my money; and the value is determined in the very moment at which I
give away the money, or exchange my commodity for another. That is
payment. That is one thing there must be in the economic process.
The second thing, which plays a similar part to payment, is the thing
to which I drew attention yesterday. It is Lending. This, as I
said, does not interfere with the concept of payment as such. Lending,
once more, is an altogether different fact, a fact which simply
exists. If I have money lent me, I can apply my Spirit to this loaned
Capital. I become a debtor; but I also become a producer. In this way,
lending plays a real economic part. If I have intellectual or
spiritual capacities in some direction, it must be possible for me to
obtain loaned Capital. No matter where I get it from, I must have it.
Thus in addition to payment there must be loan (see
Diagram 4). Here
then we have two very important factors in the economic process:
Payment and Loan.
And now by a simple deduction we must verify it here (see
diagram) by a very simple deduction you can find the third. You
will not doubt for a moment what the third thing is. We have had
Payment and Loan. The third thing is Gift. Payment, Loan
and Gift this is a real trinity of concepts, essential
to a healthy economy. There is a prevailing disinclination to include
free gift in the economic process as such, but, ladies
and gentlemen, if there is not a giving somewhere, the economic
process cannot go on at all. Imagine for a moment what we should make
of our children if we gave them nothing. We are constantly making free
gifts to the children. If we consider the economic process as a whole
as a process that goes on and on continuously Gift is
part of it. There is no escaping the fact. It is wrong to regard the
transfer of values from hand to hand, representing a process of free
gift, as something inadmissible in the economic process as such.
Precisely this one of the three is found with horror by some
people worked out in my book, The Threefold
Commonwealth, where it is shown how values are to be transferred,
how means of production, for instance, are to be transferred, by a
process really identical with giving, to one who has the faculties
necessary for managing them further. Provision must, of course, be
made that the giving is not done in a haphazard way. But in the
economic sense they are none the less free gifts, and such gifts are
absolutely necessary.
You will find it more and more to be an economic necessity. The
trinity of payment, loan and gift is there in the
economic process. Consider the matter thoroughly and you will say: In
every economic process this must be contained. Otherwise it would be
no economic process; it would lead to absurdities at every point.
People may rebel against these things for a time; but we must remember
that economic wisdom is today not very great. Those especially who
want to teach it should be under no illusions on this point. Modern
economic knowledge is by no means great. People are little inclined to
go into the real economic relationships. This is an obvious fact, so
obvious that if you look in today's Basler Nachrichten you will
find curiously enough a reflection on this very fact. Neither
Governments nor private people nowadays, it says, are inclined to
evolve real economic thinking. I think we may take it that anything
expounded in the Basler Nachrichten is likely to be obvious. It
is indeed a palpable fact and it is interesting to find it discussed
in this way. The article is interesting, inasmuch as it endeavours to
set in a glaring light the absolute impotence which prevails in the
economic sphere; interesting, too, because it says that these things
must be changed it is time Governments and individuals began to
think differently. But there the matter ends. How they are to
think differently on this you will, of course, find nothing in
the Basler Nachrichten which is also interesting!
Now it is possible to interfere in the economic process in a
disturbing way, if one does not rightly relate the one thing with the
other in this trinity. Many people today are enthusiastically
demanding the taxation of legacies (which, of course, are also gifts),
Such proposals have no deep economic significance. For we do not
lessen the value of the inheritance if, say, it has a value V and we
divide the value V into two parts, V1 and V2
giving V2 to some other party and leaving the legatee with
V1 alone. All it means is that the two together will now do
business with the original value V, and the question will be whether
he who receives V2 will husband it as advantageously for
the economic life as would the original legatee who would otherwise
have received V1 and V2 together. Everyone of
course may settle this question for himself according to his taste,
whether a single clever man, receiving the whole legacy, will husband
it better, or whether it will be better for one to receive only part
while the State receives the other part, so that the individual is
obliged to do business in conjunction with the State.
This sort of thing definitely leads us away from pure economic
thinking. It is a thinking based on resentment, on feeling. People
envy the rich heir. There may be reason for it, but we cannot look at
it only from this point of view if we claim to be thinking in an
economic sense. The point is, how must the thing be conceived in the
economic sense, for whatever else has to be done must take its start
from this. You can, of course, conceive a social organism becoming
diseased through the fact that payment is not working together in an
organic way with loan and gift, since one or the other is being
obstructed and one or the other fostered. But they will still go on
working together in some way. If you abolish giving on one side, you
merely effect a redistribution, and the question to be decided is not
whether this ought to be done, but whether it is necessarily
advantageous. Whether the individual heir alone should receive the
inheritance, or whether he must share it with the State, is a question
which must first be settled on economic grounds. Which is more
advantageous? That is the point.
The important thing is this: Free spiritual life arises almost of
necessity out of the entry of the Spirit into the economic life. As a
result of this free spiritual life, as I said just now, there will be
pure consumers so far as the past is concerned. But what of the free
spiritual life in relation to the future? Here it is productive
indirectly it is true but none the less extraordinarily
productive. Imagine the free spiritual life in the social organism
really freed, so that the individual faculties were always able to
evolve to the full. Then the free spiritual life will be able to exert
an extremely fertilising influence on the half-free spiritual life
i.e., on that spiritual life which enters into the processes of
material production. Considered in this light, the thing takes on a
decidedly economic complexion.
Anyone who can observe life with an unbiased mind will say to himself
that it is by no means a matter of indifference whether in a given
region all who are active in the free spiritual life are exterminated
(for instance, if they got nothing to consume, the right to live being
admitted only for those who work directly into the material process)
or whether really free spirits are allowed to exist within the social
organism. For the free spirits have the peculiar property of loosening
and liberating the spirituality, the gumption of the
others. They make their thinking more mobile, and these others are
thus able to work into the material process more effectively. But it
is important to remember that the free spirits are living men. You
must not try to refute me by pointing to Italy and saying: There is a
great deal of free spiritual life there, yet the economic processes
which proceed from spirit have not been stimulated to any unusual
degree. Granted, it is a free spiritual life. But it is a free
spiritual life handed down from the past. There are statues, museums
and the like; but they do not have this effect. Only what is living is
effectual that is to say, what proceeds from the free spirit
and passes on to other spiritual producers. This is what works as a
productive factor into the future, even in the economic sense. It is
certainly possible to exert a healing influence on the economic
process by giving a free field of action to free spiritual workers.
Suppose now that we have a healthy Associative life in a community.
The task of the Associations will be to arrange production in such a
way that when too many people are working in any sphere they can be
transferred to some other work. It is this vital dealing with men,
this allowing the whole social order to originate from the insight of
the Associations that matters. And when one day the Associations begin
to understand something of the influence of free spiritual life on the
economic process, we can give them a very good means of regulating the
economic circuit. I mentioned this in my Threefold
Commonwealth. The Associations will find that when free spiritual
life declines, too little is being given freely; they will
grasp the connection. They will see the connection between too little
giving and too little free spiritual work. When there is not enough
free spiritual work, they will realise that too little is being given.
When too little is being given, they will notice a decline in free
spiritual work.
There is then a very definite possibility of driving the rate of
interest on Nature-property right up to 100% by transmitting as much
Nature-property as possible in the shape of free gifts to those who
are spiritually productive. In this way you can bring the Land
question into direct connection with what works particularly into the
future. In other words, the Capital which presses to be invested, the
Capital which tends to march into mortgages and stay there, must be
given an outlet into free spiritual institutions. That is the
practical aspect. Let the Associations see to it that the money which
tends to get tied up in mortgages finds its way into free spiritual
institutions. There you have the connection of the Associative life
with the general social life. Only when you try to penetrate the
realities of economic life does it begin to dawn on you what must be
done in the one case or in the other. I do not by any means wish to
agitate that this or that must be done. I only wish to point
out what is. And this is undoubtedly true: What we can never
attain by legislative measures namely, to keep the excess
Capital away from Nature we can attain by the life and system
of Associations, diverting the Capital into free spiritual
institutions. I only say: If the one thing happens, the other will
happen too. Science, after all, has only to indicate the conditions
under which things are connected.
Last Modified: 23-Nov-2024
|
The Rudolf Steiner e.Lib is maintained by:
The e.Librarian:
elibrarian@elib.com
|
|
|
|
|