|
|
|
Rudolf Steiner e.Lib
|
|
World Economy
Rudolf Steiner e.Lib Document
|
|
World Economy
Schmidt Number: S-4926
On-line since: 13th November, 2000
Dornach, 1st August, 1922.
The formulas I tried to give yesterday are not, of course, mere
mathematical formulas, but, like the ones of which I spoke before,
they must be verified in life itself. Not only so; they must be
conceived in such a way that they actually live within the economic
process.
Today I must say a few things that may gradually lead us to understand
the way in which these things do really live in the economic process.
In the first place, everything that circulates within the total
economic process must have a certain value. On the other hand we must
also realise that many things can occur in the economic organism, the
value of which is not immediately expressed in the economic processes
themselves.
Let me give you an example that will serve as an introduction to some
further economic ideas. Unruh has described very well, in his book on
Economics, such things as the following, revealing as it were the more
hidden connections. I give only one example which I myself have
followed up and the truth of which I can vouch for purely as a matter
of observation; although Unruh is a man completely wrapped up in State
economics and, inasmuch as he thinks politically rather than
economically, is unable in the last resort to bring these things into
their right relationship.
I am referring to the price of rye in certain districts of Central
Europe. It is a striking example of the complicated way in which
things take their course in the economic process. If one hears big
farmers or estate owners speaking of their work, one often hears them
say: We make nothing on the price of rye; on the contrary, we
lose on it. What does this really mean? To begin with, it means
that these people cannot sell their rye as other things are sold
in the main, at any rate, today where the price is
composed of the costs of raw materials, the costs of production and a
certain margin of profit. Taking the actual prices of rye in this way,
we should find that they do not correspond to the costs of production
plus a certain profit. On the contrary, they fall far short. And if,
in balancing his accounts, a farmer were merely to include the actual
market prices of rye, the values he would thus insert would
undoubtedly influence the balance in a negative direction. As I said,
we can follow the matter up and it is absolutely correct; the rye is
sold, as we might say, below cost price. And yet it
cannot be so in reality; it is impossible for this to go on in
reality. Yet apparently it does go on. What happens is this:
Rye yields not only grain but also straw; and farmers who sell the
grain below cost price scarcely sell any of the straw at all. They use
it on their own farms; they use it for their cattle and strike a
balance in that way. What they lose on the rye is made up for by the
manure they get from the animals. For this is the very best manure;
there is no better. It is extremely rich in bacteria; it is the best
manure a farmer can have. Thus from the standpoint of his accounts he
gets the manure thrown in as a free gift and in this way, in the long
run, a proper balance is struck.
We are thus obliged to posit an economic concept which, though it is
most important, is comparatively little considered in the ordinary
literature of Economics. The concept I would here establish is that of
internal economies within the general economic life.
You have an internal economy whenever an economic
organism, a business, does business within itself exchanges
products within itself. That is to say, it does not sell such products
outwardly or buy them from outside, but lets them circulate within the
business itself. This I would call an internal economy as against the
general social economy. Wherever such an internal economy is in force,
it is quite possible for products to be delivered below the price
which would otherwise be economically necessary. Needless to say, this
implies that the forming of price within any economic domain is an
extremely complicated chain of events.
Such connections, as I said, have been observed as matters of pure
fact by our economists. There is another chain of events which I have
touched upon from a certain point of view and which must now be
regarded also from a different aspect. I mentioned a few days ago that
we do not take in at a glance all the links in the economic chain.
Imagine, for instance, that a cobbler falls ill and has an unskilful
doctor to attend him. He remains ill and for three weeks cannot
manufacture any boots; and so his products the boots which he
would have manufactured in the three weeks are withdrawn from
economic circulation. And now, I said, suppose he gets a skilful
doctor who makes him well within a week, so that he gets an extra
fortnight in which to go on making boots as before. Economically
speaking, we can now ask: Who manufactured the boots? Economically
speaking, undoubtedly at this moment of the economic process
the doctor did; there can be no doubt about it.
Yet here again we come to another point. For you may ask: Did the
doctor also get paid for them? No, in reality he did not; for you can
make the following calculation. Reckon it up, according to the market:
What did the boots the doctor manufactured amount to? And now if you
draw up a rather full statement of account (it would have to be a very
full one) you can set this off against what had to be spent on his
training. And you will find, in all probability, that what was spent
on his training was not so very different from the value of all the
boots he manufactured and all the stags he shot; for it is not
regarded as universally characteristic of doctors that they withdraw
from economic life, for one week only, patients who would otherwise be
withdrawn for three. Be that as it may however the final
balance emerged, we should not make a true calculation in the wider
economic sense if we did not strike the balance in this way, setting
off against the cost of his training the boots he manufactures, the
stags he shoots (assuming that he cures the huntsman quicker than
would otherwise have been the case), the corn he garners in, and so
forth. Only, of course, the economic process is very complicated, and
so the payment also proves extremely complicated.
From all this you can see: It can by no means be said with certainty,
at any given place, what is the true source of payment for a given
thing within the economic process. We must sometimes go far afield to
discover what is the real source of such payment. People who look for
mere simplicity in the economic process will never arrive at economic
concepts coinciding with reality. They will not get far enough. They
will not get at that, of which I said that it is really there
behind the formulas of Price, Supply, Demand, etc. And these
are the very things we must get at. What makes it so difficult to
estimate the economic process rightly? It is because outlay and return
are often so widely separated. That is why it is difficult to see
clearly within the economic process as a whole what it is that is paid
for, what it is that is bought, what is lent and borrowed, and what is
freely given. For example, assume for a moment that what I advocated a
few days ago is realised. Assume that the masses of Capital, arising
in one way or another, are withdrawn from the tendency to get
congested on the land and are given to the spiritual or cultural life
it may be in the form of Foundations, Scholarships or the like.
These are free gifts. And now you will begin to see what happens on
the one side of your gigantic ledger, for it must be a ledger that
comprises the real economic life in its totality. The boots the doctor
manufactures during the extra fortnight may actually contain an item
which you must look for on the other side under the heading of
free gifts. For it may well be that he had a scholarship
to help him in his training, or that he benefited by some Foundation.
In short, from this point of view you can raise the weighty question:
What are the most productive transformations of Capital in the
economic process? What are the most productive of all? Follow out such
connections as I have just described: follow especially those portions
of available Capital which go into Foundations, Scholarships and other
spiritual or cultural goods, which in the course of time
react to fertilise the whole process of spiritual production and
enterprise of every kind. You will perceive that free gifts are the
most fruitful thing of all in the whole economic process. We cannot
arrive at a healthy economic process unless, in the first place, it is
made possible for people to have something to give and, in the
second place, unless they have the goodwill and intelligence to give
what they have. Here, then, we have something which enters into the
economic process in a very peculiar way.
It is remarkable, ladies and gentlemen, that this is something which
we cannot extract from theoretical notions; it can only transpire from
a wide range of experience; and a wide range of experience will give
it you the more so, the more you follow the matter up. Indeed,
I would recommend you to keep this question in mind when you are
choosing subjects for dissertations: What becomes of the free gifts in
the whole economic process? You will find that the free gifts are the
most productive of all. Capital freely given, gift Capital, is the
most productive; loaned and borrowed Capital is less productive, in
the economic process; and the least productive is that which stands
directly under purchase and sale. That which is paid for immediately
on a transaction of purchase and sale is the least fruitful in the
economic process; that which depends on lending and comes into the
economic process through the functions of invested Capital is of
medium productivity; while that which enters into the economic process
through free gifts is of the very greatest productivity if only
for the reason that the work which would otherwise have to be done to
earn what is here given freely, or rather the product of that work, is
actually saved. We freely give the available proceeds of the economic
process, which would only do harm if they were left to congest upon
the land.
We see, therefore, that at a given moment of its evolution the
economic process gives no real information of itself. The
before and after must always be taken into account, but
the before and after cannot be taken into account unless
it is based on the judgment of men who join together in
association and who gain a corresponding insight into the past
and the future. We have to build the economic process on the insight
of those whose feet are planted within the economic process. Once
more, we come to the same conclusion: It is, generally speaking, a
difficult and lengthy business to estimate how the several factors in
the economic process play their part in the whole of human life
I mean the material life.
From a certain point of view we can speak of Trade Capital, Loaned
Capital and Industrial Capital within the economic process.
Circulating Capital is more or less covered by these three categories:
Trade Capital, Loaned Capital and Industrial Capital. Moreover, these
three are contained in the economic process in the most varied ways.
You must remember that such internal economies as we
exemplified at the beginning of today's lecture are scattered
everywhere throughout the economic process. And where you have an
economic process taking place within a larger whole, it is really
extremely difficult to say what are the respective contributions,
quantitatively speaking, of Loaned Capital, Industrial Capital and
Trade Capital to the general economic welfare. Yet it is
possible to arrive at reliable concepts, if we extend our survey to a
wide enough horizon.
Let us, to begin with, turn our attention to the economic life of
entire nations, or State-economies as we must call them, according to
the economic life of recent times. Take France, for instance; I take
it only as one example. The world-economic connections of France,
especially as they were before the War, and as they revealed
themselves in their effects during the War, are a good example of how
Loaned Capital works in the economic process on a larger scale. France
always had a certain inclination to invest Capital in loans
that is, in effect, to treat Loaned Capital (investment
Capital) literally as Loaned Capital, You are probably aware
how these things penetrated into the political sphere, clearly
illustrating the harmful effects of the coupling together of the
economic life and the life of rights (that is, the political life),
how it came out in the extensive loans made by France to Russia and
Turkey. France exported a very large amount of Loaned Capital to
Russia and to Turkey. Even in Germany, though Germany was not exactly
in her good books, French Capital found a home for instance,
when the construction of the Baghdad Railway was begun. England
withdrew, but France did not withhold her Capital from those who stood
at the head of the undertaking Siemens & Gwinner, for
example. France, therefore, was in the main a lending country. In
France one could see how Loaned Capital becomes involved in the whole
economic process.
Further and I am not defending or attacking anything, but
simply describing things objectively there is one historical
phenomenon in which you can truly recognise what are the interests of
Loaned Capital. When we turn our attention, say, to private
economies or businesses, we shall always find, as any
Bank will tell you, that the private business man is a peace-loving
man. For he knows very well that his interests and dividends will be
upset if, just as his Capital is nicely invested, a war begins to
sweep through the economic connections of the world. Political
economists always reckon with the fact that lenders are peace-loving
people. That is the reason why it is always possible to say that
France was innocent of the. War. For, the moment we want to prove that
the War was not desired in France, we need only point to the interests
of the numerous small investors and not to the interests of those who
urged on the War. In France you always have in the background those
who decidedly did not want the War. This fact of history may
show us on a large scale what is equally true on a small scale. The
man who lends the man who is the happy possessor of Capital
available for investment is essentially the man who would like
to see the economic life protected, if possible, from disturbance
either by events outside it or by catastrophic upheavals within it.
And the investor is all the fonder of tranquility because it saves him
the trouble of having to form an independent judgment. He likes to be
able to rely on the assurance of someone else that such and such is
a good thing. In our age, though public opinion has a
very good conceit of itself, there is really very little public
opinion in the sense of judgment. We may say that in our time the
possession of Capital available for investment is generally connected
with a very strong faith in authority, both in the economic life and
also in other respects. This, again, clouds the economic judgment to
no small extent. Those, for example, who are in any way officially
labelled very easily get money lent them. Personal credit is readily
given to anyone with a title or some other official label. This is
often the decisive factor. And according as this principle of
authority is more or less cultivated, we see the consequences. For, in
the one case, those who really have the stronger personal faculties
will be enabled to enter productively into the economic process, while
in the other case it will be simply men with a handle to their names
members of Chambers of Commerce and so forth and often
men who have got the name, not by reason of genuine ability but for
some quite extraneous reason. It is one thing if such people are given
the opportunity to work into the economic life, and quite another if a
man has to depend on his genuine faculties being recognised by an
untainted public judgment. Here, once again, something elusive enters
into the economic life. (In a certain community it has recently become
far too common a practice to use a certain word whenever one fails to
keep pace with things with one's clear thinking. In many places
recently, I have far too often heard this word, the
imponderables. I wish to emphasise that I desire to avoid this
word. All that I wish to point out is how these things, which we would
like to take straightforwardly, become complicated, so that we may
presently have to follow them up by somewhat curved and winding paths.
It is unnecessary, as soon as this begins to happen, to have recourse
to the convenient term the imponderables, which we have
heard ad nauseam in certain quarters.) So much, at the moment,
for Loaned Capital.
We will now go on to Industrial Capital. If we wish to study the
essence and function of Industrial Capital we shall be able to do so
especially well by observing the quick rise of industry in Germany in
the decades before the War though its history here is hardly an
edifying one. We can study it here especially well, because, under the
influence of the enterpriser spirit, Industrial Capital
arose by direct transformation out of Loaned Capital to a greater
extent in Germany in the last decades before the War than in any other
part of the world. What I said in the first lecture is most decidedly
true; In England, for example, Trade Capital was transformed gradually
into Industrial Capital. For in England industrialism evolved out of
trade, and it evolved far more slowly than in Germany, where it shot
up with immense rapidity. Industrialism exists in its pure form where
it transforms not Trade Capital but Loaned Capital into Industrial
Capital. It can therefore be best studied in its pure form in the life
of Germany.
Now the point is that Industrial Capital, if I may put it so, is
really placed between two buffers. The one buffer is the raw
product; the other is markets. Industrial Capital is
obliged, on the one hand, to look around as far as possible for the
sources of raw products and, on the other, to arrange for markets.
This is not quite so easy to study in the example of German industry.
In German industrialism you can rather study economically how
Industrial Capital functions in itself. Still, the emergence of
industrialism is evident in all countries during the nineteenth
century and on into the twentieth, and so you can observe this
standing between two buffers everywhere. Only you must
search out the true facts. As I have said, it is a good thing to
control the necessary direction orientation of our
ideas, by taking things that can be surveyed as a whole; but you will
find, if you are considering smaller economic territories, that
extraordinarily difficult paths must sometimes be traced out. It is
better to get your orientation and to derive your calculations from
wide comprehensive regions. The paths grow easier if you observe
economic organisms on a very large scale. Then, for example, you will
perceive how as a rule the concepts of Force or Might (which often
appear masked under the guise of Right or Justice) are realised most
strongly where it is a question of opening up new sources of raw
products. We can study this on a large scale, for instance, in the
Boer War, where it was mainly a question of opening up the sources of
precious metals. The Boer War was a real war for raw products. Of
course it always showed itself in a kind of mask; nevertheless it
was a war for raw products. Again, you have an example of how
the economic life unfolds in a political way, playing over into the
domain of political power you have an example of this, for
instance, in the military enterprises of Belgium which had the ivory
and rubber of the Congo as their object. Thus you can see how the
opening-up of sources of raw products takes place in the economic
life. Or again, take the case of North America, which annexed the
Spanish possessions in the West Indies, because it was looking for
sources of raw products sugar in this instance. In every case
we can see how the search for raw products very easily drives the
purely economic life into the political, towards the development of
might or force. This is the one side the one buffer, if I may
say so.
With the search for markets it is different. For, it is easy to
demonstrate from history that the search for markets does not lead
into the political life in the same way. In this case the plain fact
is that human nature does not tend so much to the use of force. We
should have to go to the nineteenth century for a rather glaring
example I mean the so-called Opium War, whereby
England conquered for herself the Chinese opium market. Even there it
did not go quite so easily by purely military means; even there
if I may put it so peaceful persuasion, peaceful politics, had
not a little to say. For when things began to grow uncomfortably hot,
a hundred and forty-one doctors were found to pronounce an expert
judgment to the effect that opium is no more harmful than tobacco or
tea. Here, then, politics peaceful politics played a
certain part. Politics in any case are always difficult to keep out.
You know the saying of Clausewitz: War is the continuation of
politics by other means. Such definitions are all very well,
but by the same method we could establish the proposition:
Divorce is the continuation of marriage by other means.
The relationships of life can always be represented in a particular
light by using this kind of logic, and people admire it! Curiously
enough, everyone sees through it at once if I say: Divorce is
the continuation of marriage by other means, but when it is
everywhere proclaimed that War is the continuation of politics
by other means, they do not notice the absurdity, but on the
contrary they admire it. In point of method, I should like to say: If
we employ this sort of logic in Political Economy, we shall not
advance a step. Speaking of this second buffer, of the hunt for
markets, we must undoubtedly admit that a far greater part is played
by human cleverness, which fluctuates between the extremes of slyness,
astuteness, and wise economic guidance. In the arranging of markets a
great deal could be seen at work of all three particularly in
the way they were arranged in those large economic domains which the
States themselves had become as Politics and Economics coalesced. The
States themselves did very much in this direction, by way of wise
guidance, and also by way of deceit, cleverness, slyness and the like.
Thus, the concepts which we require to form in respect of smaller
economic domains, concerning the relation, say, between the single
industrial undertaking and its sources of raw products and its
markets, can only be made clear and palpable by considering these
matters on a large scale.
If it is the functions of Trade Capital which we desire to study, we
should take England, especially in the period when England made her
great economic progress. This she did by means of trade; and
consequently her Trade Capital continued to increase in such a way
that England entered quite gently and imperceptibly into the new
industrialism. At the time when industrialism was transforming the
world, England already had her Trade Capital. In this early period,
therefore, we can study Trade Capital most readily in England. In more
recent times England has been chosen by Marx as a means of studying
the economic functions of industrialism; but in the earlier period
the period immediately preceding the creation of modern
industrialism going back, that is to say, to the last decades
of the eighteenth century, it is the functions of Trade Capital which
we can best study in the light of England's economic destiny. Now it
cannot be denied that here, either in the open or behind the scenes,
the essential thing is always competition. Whether on the large
scale, in the economic life of the nation as a whole, where it is
mainly based on trade, or within trade or commerce itself, competition
is the essential thing. Of course by the introduction of various ideas
of what is decent and proper conduct, it may become very fair, but it
is competition none the less. Productivity in trade such
productivity as to enable Trade Capital to be treated in the economic
process so that it eventually takes effect as Industrial Capital
such productivity depends in the last resort on the tendency of
Trade Capital to accumulate. And that is impossible without
competition. Thus we shall study the functions of Trade Capital best
of all by considering the function of competition in the
economic life.
At the same time these things are connected with historical changes.
This is indeed the case. Right up to the first third of the nineteenth
century, if we are considering the world-economy which was gradually
coming into being as a single whole (such as it was in a high degree
before the War) up to the first third of the nineteenth
century, the economic processes of trade and industry
still played the most important part in the economic life. The
blossomtime the classical age, if I may put it so of
Loaned Capital only began in the nineteenth century indeed only
towards the second third of the nineteenth century. And it is at this
point that we notice the rise of those institutions which more
especially serve the process of lending I mean the banking
system. The classical age of Loaned Capital, and with it the evolution
of the banking system, falls into the last two-thirds of the
nineteenth century and the first decades of the twentieth. With the
evolution of the banking system, borrowing and lending develops on an
ever larger scale enters more and more as a prime factor into
the economic process. But, at the same time, precisely in connection
with lending, a remarkable phenomenon appears. Through the
instrumentality of lending on a large scale, and accompanying the
expansion of the banking system, the control of the circulation of
money is withdrawn from man himself. The circulation of money has
gradually become a process taking place I can find no other
word to express it impersonally. Thus, as I said in my first
lecture, the time has actually come when money does business on its
own account, and human beings fluctuate up and down according as they
are drawn into this whole stream of money economics, money business.
They are drawn in far more than they imagine. Precisely during the
last decades of the nineteenth century, the circulation of money has
become objectified it has become impersonal. This brings me to
a peculiar phenomenon of the nineteenth century, particularly the end
of the nineteenth century. In Economics, everything depends on an
open-minded consideration of life as a whole; we must gain a clear
vision of the whole of life. The phenomenon to which I refer
appears, to begin with, in the psychological sphere, but afterwards
plays a great part in the economic life. It is this: Conditions which
were brought about in the first place by very real forces afterwards
continue rolling on by a kind of social inertia, just as a ball will
do when you have given it a certain momentum. They go rolling on and
on, even after the original impulses have ceased to be active in them.
Down to the first third of the nineteenth century, there were true
economic impulses present in the whole system of loan and investment.
Then, through the instrumentality of the banking system, these
economic impulses began to change into purely financial ones; and in
this process the whole thing became not only impersonal but unnatural.
Everything was drawn into the stream of money, as it moved itself
along. Pure money business, without any natural or personal subject
that is the end towards which, as the nineteenth century drew
to a close, everything which had originally been upheld by a personal
and natural subject was gravitating.
Strangely enough, this subjectless economic life, this
subjectless circulation of money, was accompanied by
another phenomenon. It was this: Political States themselves began to
do business out of economic impulses; it was out of such impulses, for
example, that they began to colonise. We shall see later what
influence colonising has; de-colonising, too, will have to be
considered in this connection. We can observe very well, as a real
economic process, the significance of colonisation in the case of
England. Fundamentally speaking, England scarcely ever went beyond the
kind of colonisation which we may perhaps describe as
Imperialism with an objective content. Such Imperialism,
I mean, as contains a real economic substance economic meaning.
But if, on the other hand, you take the case of Germany, you need only
look at the colonial accounts
and you will see that German colonisation was burdened from the start
with an adverse balance. There were at most tiny areas which showed a
favourable balance. And in other countries too the tendency crept in,
merely to enlarge themselves by acquiring colonies. Isolated people
Hilferding, for instance, in his book Finanzkapital,
published in Vienna in 1910 actually called this process
objectless Imperialism Imperialism without an
object.
These two modern phenomena are particularly instructive: on the one
hand, the subjectless circulation of money, impersonal and unnatural;
and, on the other hand, objectless Imperialism. Characteristic as they
both are of large-scale economy, their appearance together suggests
that the one depends upon the other.
Such a thing is purely psychological, to begin with, though in the
further course it becomes economic; for if we have unproductive
colonies we must pay for them and that means that they at once
affect the economic life.
So much for what we had to discuss today.
Last Modified: 02-Nov-2024
|
The Rudolf Steiner e.Lib is maintained by:
The e.Librarian:
elibrarian@elib.com
|
|
|
|
|